Answer Key
University:
Massachusetts Institute of TechnologyCourse:
15.501/516 | AccountingAcademic year:
2023
Views:
257
Pages:
5
Author:
Jase Harrington
80,000 I P>80,000 40,000 P>40,000 I 160,000-P>40,000 I It does not make any difference from an efficiency perspective which firm buys the other - the same value is created in each case. There is a range of selling prices that would leave both firms better off, reflecting precisely the fact that there is a gain from trade. Of course the actual selling price will determine how that gain from trade is divided between the two firms. We can think of this in terms of the Coase theorem that we discussed in the section on externalities - with a small number of agents and a situation with an externality, we would expect that negotiation between the parties would come up with a way of internalizing the externality. As is usual with the Coase theorem, there can be many solutions - they all reach the efficient outcome but can differ in terms of the distribution of surplus. iv) What is the economic rationale for the merger? Why is the vertical structure inefficient and how does the merger create value? The vertical structure is inefficient because of the DOUBLE MARGINALIZATION. There is an externality at work here. The retailer takes the producer price as given and maximizes its profits. As it is a monopolist it does so by restricting the quantity of sales. Although this is profit maximizing for Better Buy, it does not take into account that the restriction of sales reduces the profits of Grapefruit, since Grapefruit is also earning a margin on its sales. This negative externality is not taken into account in the pricing at retail level, and since negative externalities are done to excess there is too little output sold relative to the fully profit maximizing arrangement. The merger, by rationalizing the decision making, essentially removing the intermediate pricing step allows this externality to be fully internalized so the efficient outcome for the firms together can be reached. We can see that the inefficiency is related to the monopoly pricing by comparing the outcome if the retail sector were competitive. If retail is competitive then so the demand curve upstream is: And profit maximization implies that 900-2Q=100 so that Q=400 - the profit maximizing quantity for the structure as a whole. Equivalently, suppose the computer manufacturer market is competitive so that Grapefruit cannot charge a mark-up. The marginal costs of Better Buy are $200 and the MR curve from the market demand is P=1000-2Q. Profit Maximization again gives 1000-2Q=200 and Q=400 the efficient quantity of output. c) Thinking about welfare more generally, the merger allows the firms to exploit their monopoly power more effectively. Does this come at the cost of consumer surplus? Should the merger be permitted on the grounds of economic efficiency? What are the welfare implications of this merger? Compared to perfect competition, consumers always suffer when firms get to exploit their monopoly power. However in the case of double marginalization consumers also gain. The reason is that prices are higher and quantities lower in the non-integrated arrangement - the non-integrated firms restrict output beyond that which a single monopolist would choose - profits actually increase as the firms increase output closer towards the competitive level. This illustrates an important difference between horizontal and vertical mergers. Horizontal mergers will often reduce competition and have negative implications for consumers. Vertical mergers can rationalize the production structure to the benefit of both producers and consumers.
Excercise Solution Double Marginalization Exercise
Get your assignment done in just 3 hours. Quick, easy, and available 24/7.
Report
Tell us what’s wrong with it:
Thanks, got it!
We will moderate it soon!
Our EduBirdie Experts Are Here for You 24/7! Just fill out a form and let us know how we can assist you.
Enter your email below and get instant access to your document